Create a free account, or log in

Why handing NBN oversight to a new regulator is a recipe for failure

Both the Harper competition policy review, and the more recent Vertigan NBN market and regulatory review have widespread implications for economic regulation. The reports are different in scope and their respective analysis of the Australian marketplace, but both share a determination to see the regulatory role of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) cut […]
The Conversation
Why handing NBN oversight to a new regulator is a recipe for failure

Both the Harper competition policy review, and the more recent Vertigan NBN market and regulatory review have widespread implications for economic regulation.

The reports are different in scope and their respective analysis of the Australian marketplace, but both share a determination to see the regulatory role of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) cut back.

Harper review

Despite acknowledging that there are synergies among the functions of competition, consumer protection and economic regulation that can assist the ACCC perform its role, Harper recommends a split.

Under his proposal the access and pricing functions currently exercised by the ACCC, including arbitration functions under the National Access Regime, declarations and access arbitration functions under the telecommunications access regime, and price monitoring functions under the Water Act 2007 would be handed over to a new specialist access regulatory body.

Vertigan panel

The ACCC is currently responsible for assessing and enforcing the terms and conditions of access to services on the NBN and for the Structural Separation Undertaking given by Telstra. It is also responsible for setting wholesale prices and terms and conditions of access for NBN services and investigating claims of antiโ€competitive conduct by carriers.

The Vertigan report recommends the establishment of:

โ€œa โ€˜networks regulatorโ€™, which should be a specialised body with its own leadership and staff. This entityโ€™s sole responsibility would be the economic regulation of network industries.โ€

This recommendation is made despite the reportโ€™s authors acknowledging, with one exception, submissions were generally supportive of the ACCC and felt that it should remain the institution to regulate telecommunications competition and consumer policy.

In fact the report notes that โ€œMost submitters either made no suggestions for change or sought marginal improvementsโ€.

Vertigan provides a wholly inadequate rationale for stripping the ACCC of its telecommunications functions. The essence of his finding is that โ€œthe earlier rationale for vesting those arrangements in the ACCC โ€“ namely, the expected move to an approach primarily reliant on nonโ€industryโ€specific competition policy instruments โ€“ is no longer valid”.

He also argues that โ€œthe sheer scale of the regulatory tasks that lie ahead and the high costs of regulatory error suggest a need for those tasks to be undertaken by an entity whose leadership is focused on regulatory functions”.

In my opinion, returning to industry-focused regulation for communications would be a disaster. In 1997 the government closed down Austel, an industry regulator tasked with protecting consumers and carriers from unfair competition and practices. At the time industry and policy makers convinced themselves that in a few short years, no special rules would be needed. Now it seems they have convinced themselves that communications is so complex the nationโ€™s competition regulator canโ€™t handle it.

Story continues on page 2. Please click below.