Create a free account, or log in

Equal pay for equal work? Why the gender pay gap remains 50 years on

Half a century after we recognised the principle of equal pay for equal work, the gender pay gap and ‘women’s work’ remain.
The Conversation
equal pay gender pay gap
Source: AAP/Joe Giddens/PA Wire.

June 19, 2019 is the 50th anniversary of Australiaโ€™s industrial relations system endorsing the principle of โ€œequal pay for equal workโ€.

Yet, five decades on, a gender pay gap remains.

The 1969 decision was a breakthrough, but also highlighted the problem of putting principle into practice, given a legacy of past decisions being based on clear notions of โ€œmaleโ€ and โ€œfemaleโ€ jobs.

While various factors contribute to the overall gender pay gap, about 30% is due to gender concentrations by industry and occupation.

Decisions dating back a century have contributed to the unequal wage patterns we still see today, with female-dominated jobs clustered at the lower end of the pay spectrum.

ABS Census of Population and Housing 2016, and ABS Average Weekly Earnings 2018 (Cat No. 6302.0)., Author provided

Itโ€™s difficult to untangle todayโ€™s gender pay gap from the pages of history.

A living wage, but based on men

A gap between menโ€™s and womenโ€™s pay was effectively established early in Australiaโ€™s centralised wage-fixing system.

In 1907, the first landmark decision of the new Commonwealth Court of Conciliation and Arbitration set down the principle of the โ€œfamilyโ€ or โ€œlivingโ€ wage.

In the Harvester Case (stemming from a pay dispute at Sunshine Harvester, a Victorian maker of farming equipment), the court decided 7 shillings a day was the minimum pay needed by an unskilled labourer โ€“ on the basis that the labourer was male and needed to provide for a wife and three children.

The decision laid the foundation for a national minimum wage, but also left female workers out of the picture.

Equal pay, but only for menโ€™s work

The underlying presumption that a woman didnโ€™t need to be paid as much as a man was confirmed by Justice Henry Bourne Higgins, the president of the Court of Conciliation and Arbitration, in the Fruit Pickers Case of 1912.

In this, the courtโ€™s first explicit ruling on womenโ€™s pay, Justice Higgins declared women should be paid the same as men โ€“ but only when they did jobs predominantly performed by men (such as blacksmiths) or were โ€œin competitionโ€ with men (such as fruit-picking). This was out of concern that allowing a lower pay rate for women could put men out of work.

In jobs undertaken only or mainly by women, such as packing fruit, it was a different matter. A womanโ€™s wage could be lower than a manโ€™s, Justice Higgins said, under the assumption that women โ€œhave to find their own food, shelter, and clothing; not food, shelter and clothing of a familyโ€.

It was men, he explained, who had the obligation to provide for their wife and children:

“How is such a minimum applicable to the case of a woman picker? She is not, unless perhaps in very exceptional circumstances, under any such obligation.”

Justice Higgins set the minimum pay for fruit-packing jobs โ€“ โ€œin which men are hardly ever employedโ€ โ€“ at 75% of that for fruit-picking. In the Clothing Trades Case of 1919, more concern about costs led him to decide the basic wage for women should be 54% of menโ€™s.

This gender discrepancy in pay narrowed to 75% with World War II, when women stepped into jobs vacated by men and special regulations were enacted. This 75% rate was accepted as the standard in the 1949-50 Basic Wage Case.

Accepting equal pay, in principle

As social attitudes evolved, the 1950s and 1960s saw more women joining the paid workforce. Pressure grew to match international conventions on equal pay. Unions led by the Australasian Meat Industry Employees Union, with a young Bob Hawke serving as their lead advocate, took up the cause.

In the 1969 Equal Pay Case, the Conciliation and Arbitration Commission (which had replaced the Court) finally accepted the principle of equal pay for equal work.

It tempered this acceptance, however, by acknowledging that putting the principle into practice would be complex:

While we accept the concept of โ€œequal pay for equal workโ€ implying as it does the elimination of discrimination based on sex alone, we realise that the concept is difficult of precise definition and even more difficult to apply with precision.

The โ€œmere similarity in name of male and female classificationsโ€, the commission said, โ€œmay not be enough to establish that males and females do work of a like natureโ€.

This meant the principle only immediately applied to women doing exactly the same work as men, and employed in predominantly male occupations. Fewer than one in five working women benefited from the outcome.

Three years later, the 1972 Equal Pay Case expanded on the 1969 principle to encompass โ€œequal pay for work of equal valueโ€, with a single rate for a job, regardless of gender.

But with women and men often finding themselves in different types of work โ€“ and the nature of that work often differing vastly โ€“ the dilemma of figuring out how to measure โ€œwork of equal valueโ€ remained. It persists to this day.

Finding a โ€˜comparableโ€™ male job

Todayโ€™s Fair Work Commission has inherited the legacy of its past judgements.

To agree a low wage rate in an occupation dominated by females is an issue of gender inequality, Australiaโ€™s Fair Work Act requires identifying a โ€œcomparableโ€ male occupation.

This means pointing to a job chiefly performed by men that is similar to the female job in skill requirements and job responsibility but higher paid. History shows finding such a โ€œcomparatorโ€ occupational group has been hard to achieve.

Itโ€™s a problem faced by those arguing for higher wages in occupations such as childcare.

It leads us to ask: how can we meaningfully measure and compare the value of jobs that are so different in nature?

Itโ€™s an especially important question for jobs in areas such as childcare, schooling and health services โ€“ which generate society-wide benefits but are not necessarily well-paid.

When the wider benefits of a job are not reflected by the market wage, this creates what economists call a market failure. It spells a role for governments to step in and correct it.

One innovative approach could be to use occupation-targeted lower income tax rates for jobs with high societal value.

Leonora Risse is aย Vice-Chancellor’s Postdoctoral Fellow at RMIT University.

This article is republished fromย The Conversationย under a Creative Commons license. Read theย original article.

NOW READ:ย Thirteen inspiring women in Australian startups and small business

NOW READ:ย Women in technology: Fighting inequality starts within yourself